Conclusion
The
Valley has saddled the country with an immense surplus
of fruit for which an outlet must be found, either at
home or abroad. By whatever means this is done, it must
be based on sound economic principles, which when put
into practice will afford the grower a livelihood. Until
that is done, the final installment of the history of
the fruit industry in the Okanagan Valley can not be written.
1
The
abandonment of the orderly marketing system marked the conclusion
to a sad and divisive period in the history of the Okanagan fruit
industry. Confronted by the fallout from successive freezes in the
late 1960s, a significant number of growers once again became disillusioned
with the marketing structures utilized to sell their fruit. The
single-desk and orderly marketing system had, after all, been intended
to buffer the average grower against the vicissitudes of the open
market place, providing, in turn, the economic stability that a
fragmented orchard landscape had never been capable of generating.
This had been the motivating force behind the removal of individual
rights from the marketing process in the 1920s and 1930s: the conviction
that only through collective action could prosperity be achieved.
Unfortunately, in periods of abnormal climactic conditions such
as the events that occurred between 1949-55, this marketing system
could, and did, break down, unable on occasion to return to producers
even the minimum costs of production. The causal factors behind
these failings could be traced directly back to the development
of a large-scale, intensive fruit-growing district in the Okanagan,
and the question of whether such a project had been an ideal utilization
of the land base. Both local boosters and the provincial government
had attempted to supersede the limitations of the natural environment
in erecting their respective orchard communities. Subsequently condemned
to seek stability through local institutions and organizations extraneous
of the orchard unit, growers ultimately resolved to pursue a form
of mandatory central selling following a generation of financial
bloodletting exacerbated by an uncoordinated, voluntary approach
to marketing. Despite the indisputable successes of the single-desk
and orderly marketing throughout the 1940s, they were only ever
coping mechanisms: the tools needed to protect and further the interests
of all growers in the production and marketing of their fruit in
an inhospitable natural environment.
Unfortunately,
active regulation of the market through these mechanisms did not
allow growers to become masters of their surroundings. The single-desk
simply moderated the advantages and disadvantages, created wholly
by chance, between orchards in the marketing and production of fruit.
Being a compromise solution itself, the social and economic networks
that came to constitute the "industry" after 1939 were
undoubtedly compelled to exercise flexibility on the issue of orchard
utilization during periods of price volatility. Despite all the
moves towards co-operation, it would be the orchard unit that remained
under individual control throughout this period. An ironic anachronism
to some,2 the unencumbered
right of growers to dispose of their property in any manner they
deemed appropriate came to be an integral component in the continued
operation and acceptance of the single-desk. This was a dynamic
shaped by a local environment in which any degree of autonomy returned
to the individual in marketing would allow inequalities in location
or production to once again be exploited to the detriment of the
entire industry. If the single-desk and orderly marketing were to
succeed as a mandatory, co-operative venture, no member could have
a privilege such as selling to the market early or avoiding the
collective costs of marketing. Confined to upholding a rigid and
inflexible marketing structure and confronted by a natural landscape
that made the consistent, year-over-year return of a basic level
of income to growers increasingly difficult after 1949, the unencumbered
sale of orchard land became a safety valve. The sale of orchards
effectively deflected any serious criticisms or re-evaluations concerning
the BCFGA's one-dimensional evolution.
The
selling of orchard land effectively muted the appeal of reformers
and dissidents seeking broad, wholesale changes to existing industry
hierarchies in the 1950s and 1960s. The failure of dissidents to
loosen the monopoly status of BC Tree Fruits, or of reformers to
overthrow the incumbent leadership of the industry, must be weighed
against the slow and steady erosion of the orchard landscape in
this same period. The composition of the general grower body was
one still dominated by individuals who could well remember the economic
turmoil that had precipitated the collapse of the Associated Growers
in 1923 and the dark days of the "cent-a-pound-or-on-the-ground"
strike a decade later. Battling the Fruit Board for more autonomy
was perceived by this generation as a zero-sum game, explaining
the higher levels of support shown to the reformist Penticton Ginger
Group versus the rebel Canadian Fruit Growers' Association. The
option of continuing to subdivide one's holdings in order to stem
the losses from the orchard operation remained a far more palatable
option than illegal peddling, and one not initially at cross-purposes
with the long-term viability of the fruit industry. These practices,
however, would indeed soon become untenable, as the valley was subjected
to a new dynamic in land-use trends: urbanization.
In a
sense, the final report of the MacPhee Royal Commission released
in 1958 marked a pivotal and final opportunity for the industry
to attempt to reverse the course it had embarked upon. The Hope-Princeton
Highway, connecting the important Oliver-Osoyoos fruit district
with the large urban centers of the coast, had already been open
for a decade and was slowly transforming traditional marketing channels
to the detriment of BC Tree Fruits and the Fruit Board. With improved
vehicle access came a new opportunity for growers fronting some
of the valley's busiest motorways to service the new traffic through
roadside stands. While the penetration of these grower-owned outlets
was limited, and their legality hotly contested in the 1950s, the
completion of the Trans-Canada Highway was only a mere four years
away. After 1962, the valley would be opened to all manner of vehicle
traffic coming in from the Prairies, followed shortly thereafter
by a new wave of economic growth and diversification. Meaningful
engagement of MacPhee's findings on orchard size, economical units,
and packinghouse amalgamation may have helped reverse the erosion
of the orchard landscape that had already seen Salmon Arm and the
Kootenays no longer producing commercially meaningful volumes of
fruit. That the BCFGA (and, by extension all growers) allowed debate
following MacPhee's findings to be polarized by dissidents seeking
to overthrow the marketing system obscures the centrality of unfettered
land-use decisions to the continued operation of the single-desk.
The more apparent that the shortcomings of the marketing system
became after 1958, the more growers looked towards their land holdings
as retirement nest eggs. MacPhee's attempt, therefore, to define
a minimum orchard size below which production would not be economically
feasible threatened entrenched preconceptions within the industry.
The BCFGA had been created to bring stability to the small-scale,
family run orchard, and had presided over the unregulated subdivision
of orchards throughout the 1940s and 1950s. Its democratic processes
were dominated by growers operating on smaller acreages, growers
who continued to believe that their orchards were viable, if for
no other reason than to maintain the property value. The single-desk
was an integral part of this system, and for the BCFGA to actively
engage the issue of orchard size and land-use patterns would have
likely precipitated a re-evaluation of the entire marketing structure.
The larger, corporate orchards of Washington State operated their
own packinghouses, marketing their fruit directly. If the Okanagan
fruit industry was to move towards a similar model, then it stood
to reason that the commitment to the single-desk and orderly marketing
would need to be re-thought.
This
inability to conduct a wider-ranging and more meaningful debate
on the future of the industry had far-reaching consequences for
the maintenance of central selling. The turmoil and uncertainty
that accompanied the two freezes of the early 1950s provided a more
conducive atmosphere for the re-emergence of a small but vocal minority
of growers who had never been able to accept the more illiberal
requirements of the single-desk. In the early history of the fruit
industry this group had been composed of ardent individualists,
growers who possessed practical experience marketing their produce
and who preferred to rely upon their own initiative over any collective
venture. Following the implementation of BC Tree Fruits as the sole
selling agency, the composition of these dissidents had been changing.
An influx of immigration during and after the war along with a general
turnover in the overall demographic profile of growers combined
to bring people into the valley who were unaware of the industry's
history, and who had a hard time accepting the restrictions of central
selling. Most of these new-generation dissidents had come to the
Okanagan after 1940, and none had any practical experience marketing
their own crop. Neither did these growers realize or accept that
the prices they did receive from bootlegging fruit to the coast
bore a direct correlation to the operation of the orderly marketing
system - a mechanism they did not fully understand. Although they
were relegated to the margins of the industry in the early 1960s,
it was almost inevitable that, following the next short-term income
crisis, there would be a return of dissent.
Aiding
the dissidents' cause was the economic boom that had slowly started
to reshape the face of the valley by the end of the 1960s. The Trans-Canada
highway was already transforming the Okanagan into a desirable summer
tourist destination, stimulating the emergence of a service sector
geared to the expanding tourist industry. Federally sponsored rural
development programs designed to encourage industrial development
and off-farm employment opportunities were also diversifying the
valley's economy away from agriculture. In a narrow, mountain valley
such as the Okanagan, the limited land base precipitated an intense
competition for land, one in which producers were poorly positioned
to compete. As growers struggled after consecutive freezes between
1965 and 1969, the temptation to sell into an inflated real-estate
market being sustained by urban, residential demand proved too great.
The industry's marketing structures had begun to falter following
the 1965 freeze, eventually to fail in 1970 as cash transfers, expected
by growers from the sales agency, never materialized at local packinghouses.
An important means of exiting the industry following the '65 freeze,
the continued sale of orchard land became crucial entering the new
decade. Not surprisingly, dissidents re-emerged to exploit this
grower unrest, but for two years their message remained relatively
muted. Apart from a minor increase in the number of growers illegally
bootlegging fruit to the coast, the unencumbered sale of orchard
land was once again buttressing the continued operation of the single-desk.
The
broader implications of urbanization were ultimately realized in
1972, when a newly elected provincial government began the process
of instituting far-reaching restrictions on the conversion of farmland
throughout British Columbia. This inhibited the sale of orchard
land in the Okanagan, closing what had been a viable avenue of operation
for many growers. The subsequent unrest amongst the growers provided
fertile ground for the dissidents to push for a relaxation of the
rules surrounding the single-desk. As a result of its one-dimensional
evolution, the BCFGA was poorly positioned to mount a convincing
counter-campaign to these dissidents, especially when most growers
were suffering financially due to successive frosts. The result
was a usurpation of power by the provincial government through the
Land Commission Act, which provided the government control
over the disposition of land; and its companion piece of legislation
the Farm Income Assurance Act, which provided growers with
a guaranteed income. The only argument the association could make
was that it had the rule of law on its side, but even this claim
proved futile. Through reckless inaction and political calculation,
the provincial government abandoned the Fruit Board in its enforcement
of the Natural Products Marketing Act, denying the industry
one of the structures it had operated on for over thirty years.
Following
the defeat of the New Democratic Party government in 1975, the province's
commitment to growers vis-à-vis subsidies and other economic
transfers slowly receded. By the mid-1980s the provincial government
began reducing coverage under the act, and in 1993 the subsidies
were ended all together - prompting the BCFGA to call for the abolition
of the Agricultural Land Reserve. Currently, any public assistance
made available to growers is done without any requirement that eligibility
be dependent on participation in the Association. This has resulted
in a precipitous drop in membership: where there was once over three
thousand growers belonging to the BCFGA, in 2001 that number was
slightly more than six hundred.3
The decline has been even more precipitous in the short-term as
membership declined by two hundred between 1999 and 2000, and registered
a 50 percent decline over the previous seven years.4
Orchard acreage has suffered a similar drop, decreasing from twenty-six
thousand acres in 1993, to about nineteen thousand in 2000, of which
BCFGA members only farm ten thousand acres.5
In the
end, what conclusions are there to be drawn from the fate of the
Okanagan fruit growers and their system of central selling and orderly
marketing? It does remain somewhat ironic that these growers, as
one of the first commodity groups in Canada to avail themselves
of the marketing legislation introduced in the 1920s and 1930s,
can now be looked upon as having provided an early roadmap to the
challenges which other regulated agricultural industries now experience.
The issue of excessive institutionalization or specialization of
the marketing organization, along with an accompanying and persistent
avoidance of broader issues that face producers, which weakened
the BCFGA throughout the 1960s, is a charge that has routinely been
made against the Canadian Wheat Board (CWB) in recent years.6
The CWB's ability to deal with "dissidents," and others
opposed to its dominant position within the marketplace, may well
depend on an avoidance of the organizational failure that beset
the BCFGA. When further looking at events in the Okanagan, it is
important to understand that urban development is not the only form
of land-use change that can be detrimental to a marketing system.
Changing land-use patterns and growing disparity among producers
within an entirely rural setting can have the same impact, as was
evident in Saskatchewan throughout the 1990s as the profitability
of hog production spurred the creation of anomalous, large-scale,
intensive hog operations. The marketing needs of these new operators
were deemed to differ radically from those of more traditional,
small-scale hog producers.7
As a result, the province's hog marketing system was dismantled
in the late 1990s, and all Prairie hog producers now find themselves
confronted with the same challenge of competing in an unregulated
marketplace, for better or worse.
The
final cautionary tale to be drawn from the fruit growers is the
impact that a small but vocal minority of dissidents can have on
the long-term success of a controlled marketing system. It can easily
be argued that all marketing schemes are subject to this kind of
pressure, but in a British Columbia context probably two of the
more susceptible commodity groups are found in the Fraser Valley
close to the large urban market of Vancouver and the many media
outlets of the province. Every few years disgruntled producers can
be relied upon to air their grievances concerning the marketing
boards before the media, and occasionally a more organized opposition
of dissidents will coalesce with the intent of doing away with all
restrictions. Generally, debate is framed in the context of a monopolistic
entity restricting access to a foodstuff to the detriment of the
average consumer. Such a discourse, however, ignores the benefits
of regulation including quality control, regional equity, and promoting
a healthy domestic agricultural industry. Where such collective
benefits may be present, it is important that a minority of producers
not drive the removal of a marketing scheme. The case of the land
reserve in the 1970s suggests it may be particularly dangerous when
agricultural policy is made abruptly by a government that is out
of touch with agricultural or regional realities, and subject to
pressure from a small but vocal group of producers.
The
story of the BCFGA is important because it was one of the first
mandated collective marketing schemes; but it is only a single case.
It could be that the BCFGA's story was shaped by dynamics peculiar
to its region, market, and membership. Only similar research on
other cases of orderly marketing, sensitive to regional and environmental
and other factors, could determine how widely the same considerations
applied. This thesis is only a beginning. Too little research has
been done on the processes of collective marketing and its breakdown
into environmental or institutional relationships.
Over sixty-five
years ago, the historian Margaret Ormsby, the child of a fruit grower
herself, suggested that the final installment in the history of
the Okanagan fruit industry would only be written with the institution
of an equitable and economically sound marketing system. For thirty
years, the single-desk and orderly marketing, the "product
of so much blood, sweat, toil and tears" seemed to affirm her
assertion.8 Growers had found
a means in which to organize their industry, running it in a manner
that tried to benefit everyone. But changes have indeed taken place,
and the final installment in the history of the fruit growers will
most likely be one that few had ever predicted.
___________________________________________________________________________
Footnotes:
1.
Margaret Ormsby, "Fruit Marketing in the Okanagan Valley
of British Columbia," Agricultural History, Volume
9, No. 2, April 1935, p. 97.
2. Colin Reeves asserts that in order for
commercial orcharding to be economically viable in the Kelowna
area, it was necessary to nullify the adverse affects of a dispersed
marketing system. This was achieved through the creation of large
co-operative organizations. He then argues that it is ironic,
if not surprising that Kelowna can only be understood as an extension
of co-operative grower control over all aspects of the industry
except the orchards themselves. See Colin Reeves, "The Establishment
of the Kelowna Orcharding Area: A Study of Accommodation to Site
and Location," Unpublished MA Thesis, University of British
Columbia, 1973, pp. 5-6.
3. Oliver Chronicle, "Falling
BCFGA membership reaching crisis point," January 31, 2000,
http://www.oliverchronicle.com/2000_31.htm (January 22, 2002).
4. The 50 percent decline over seven years
would be for the period 1993-2000. Ibid.
5. Ibid.
6. For more info on this topic please refer
to Hartley Furtan and Andy Schmitz's The Canadian Wheat Board:
Marketing in the New Millennium (2000).
7. Most of the hog output in Saskatchewan
now comes from farms with over 4,000 animals, while only four
percent of the pork originates on farms with less then 100 hogs
- even though farms operating at this level account for over 2,000
producers. The potential markets for these diverse players differed
substantially, and the single desk system was deemed incapable
of meeting everyone's needs. Frontier Centre for Public Policy,
"Saskatchewan Restructures Pork," November 1997,
http://www.fcpp.org/publications/policy_notes/new_economy/marketing_boards/nov1097.html
(April 1, 2002).
8. Arthur Garrish, "The Demise of
the Orderly Marketing System," Okanagan Historical Society,
50th Report, 1986, pp. 60-61.
|
|
|
©
Copyright Christopher John Garrish. All rights reserved.
|